Студопедия — Сатьянанда Сарасвати
Студопедия Главная Случайная страница Обратная связь

Разделы: Автомобили Астрономия Биология География Дом и сад Другие языки Другое Информатика История Культура Литература Логика Математика Медицина Металлургия Механика Образование Охрана труда Педагогика Политика Право Психология Религия Риторика Социология Спорт Строительство Технология Туризм Физика Философия Финансы Химия Черчение Экология Экономика Электроника

Сатьянанда Сарасвати






Abstract

The Policy Research Working Paper Series disseminates the findings of work in progress to encourage the exchange of ideas about development

issues. An objective of the series is to get the findings out quickly, even if the presentations are less than fully polished. The papers carry the

names of the authors and should be cited accordingly. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this paper are entirely those

of the authors. They do not necessarily represent the views of the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development/World Bank and

its affiliated organizations, or those of the Executive Directors of the World Bank or the governments they represent.

Policy Research Working Paper 5255

This paper summarizes the estimates of what Russia will

get from World Trade Organization accession and why.

A key finding is the estimate that Russia will gain about

$53 billion per year in the medium term from World

Trade Organization accession and $177 billion per year

in the long term, due largely to its own commitments

to reform its own business services sectors. The paper

summarizes the principal reform commitments that

Russia has undertaken as part of its World Trade

Organization accession negotiations, and compares them

with those of other countries that have acceded to the

World Trade Organization. It finds that the Russian

commitments represent a liberal offer to the members

of the World Trade Organization for admission, but

This paper—a product of the Trade and Integration Team, Development Research Group—is part of a larger effort in the

department to assess the impact of liberalization of trade and foreign direct investment on growth and poverty reduction.

Policy Research Working Papers are also posted on the Web at http://econ.worldbank.org. The author may be contacted

at [email protected].

they are typical of other transition countries that have

acceded to the World Trade Organization. The authors

discuss the outstanding issues in the Russian World Trade

Organizaiton accession negotiations, and explain why

Russian accession will result in the elimination of the

Jackson-Vanik Amendment against Russia. They discuss

Russian policies to attract foreign direct investment,

including an assessment of the impact of the 2008 law

on strategic sectors and the increased role of the state in

the economy. Finally, the authors assess the importance

of Russian accession to Russia and to the international

trading community, and suggestions for most efficiently

meeting the government’s diversification objective.

Russian Trade and Foreign Direct Investment Policy at the Crossroads

David Tarr1

and

Natalya Volchkova2

1 Consultant and former Lead Economist, The World Bank and adjunct Professor of Economics, the New

Economic School in Moscow.

2 Professor of Economics, the New Economic School in Moscow

Russian Trade and Foreign Direct Investment Policy at the Crossroads

David Tarr

and

Natalya Volchkova

I. Introduction

As of June 2009, there were 153 member countries of the World Trade Organization (WTO).

Trade among them represented 97 percent of the world's trade turnover, including over 94 percent

of the foodstuffs. Russia is the largest economy outside the WTO and—along with Azerbaijan,

Belarus, Kazakhstan, Tajikistan and Uzbekistan of the Commonwealth of Independent States

(CIS)—is among the 29 countries that were attempting to accede to the WTO in August 2009.

The Working Party on accession of the Russian Federation to the WTO was established June 16,

1993. The WTO Working Party on Russia’s accession comprises about 60 countries, and is the

largest such Working Party in the history of the WTO. By the spring of 2007, Russia has

successfully concluded bilateral agreements with all the members of its Working Party who

sought a bilateral except Georgia.3 The focus now is on the multilateral phase of the negotiations.

Considerable progress on the multilateral issues was made so that by mid-2008, only three issues

remained to be resolved; but these three issues remained on the table in mid-2009.

During the first Administration of President Vladimir Putin, Russia actively sought membership

in the WTO, and this was seen as part of a strategy of an open economy model of economic

development. As we discuss below, however, in recent years Russia, in its efforts to diversify the

economy away from energy and raw material dependence, has employed several industrial policy

and import-substitution-industrialization measures. We discuss why we believe that Russia’s

trade and foreign direct investment policies for the future are at a critical crossroads.

In section II, we summarize the estimates of what Russia will get from WTO accession and why.

WTO accession is a long process--as mentioned Russia has been negotiating its accession since

1993. The Russian Duma has already passed into law about 42 significant packages of legislation

to conform to WTO requirements,4 and will implement selected other commitments on an agreed

schedule up to several years after its actual accession. The studies mentioned below quantitatively

3 Georgia earlier had agreed to a bilateral agreement on Russian WTO accession but has withdrawn from

that agreement.

4 During the first Administration of President Vladimir Putin, the chief negotiator for WTO accession of the

Russian Federation prepared a matrix of 42 packages of legislation that he needed to have prepared and

passed by the Russian Duma in order to conform to WTO accession requirements.

estimate the collective impact of all these commitments taken during the long accession process.

These studies estimate that Russia will gain about $40 billion per year in the medium term and

$132 billion per year in the long term, due largely to its own commitments to reform in the

business services sectors. In section III, we summarize the principal Russian reform commitments

at the WTO, and compare those commitments in section IV to those of other acceding countries

to the WTO. We find that the demands on Russia are comparable to other Transition countries. In

section V, we discuss remaining issues in accession. In section VI, we discuss prospects for the

Russia-Belarus-Kazakahstan customs union and related WTO accession issues. In section VII, we

explain why Russian WTO accession will result in the elimination of the Jackson-Vanik

Amendment against Russia. In section VIII, we discuss Russian policies to attract foreign direct

investment. In section IX, we argue that uniform tariffs would yield substantial benefits for

Russia, but pre-shipment inspection would yield marginal benefits at best. In the concluding

section we argue that Russian WTO accession is crucial to Russia. The key point is that due to

pressure from the international community, WTO accession represents a unique historical

opportunity to overcome the usual domestic political economy forces that lead to excessive

protection. On the other hand, the economic gains to the international community from Russian

accession will likely be small. Finally, what is required for diversification is institutional reform

to improve the business climate, especially for small and medium enterprises.

II. Estimates of WTO Accession Impacts on Russia: Russia will gain from $53 billion to

$177 billion per year

WTO accession is a process that may be used as an important tool for economic development.

WTO accession will impact on a wide range of policies and institutions, including tariff policy,

customs administration, standards, rights of foreign investors (especially in services), agricultural

policy, intellectual property and possibly government procurement. It therefore represents a time

for evaluation of a very wide range of regulation and an opportunity to implement important

trade, foreign direct investment and institutional changes.

As mentioned above, Russia has passed about 42 packages of legislation to conform to WTO

requirements. In many cases, Russia has implemented changes prior to accession to adapt to post-

WTO requirements; in other cases, the commitments may be implemented only several years

after accession due to a negotiated adjustment period. These cumulative changes will move the

economy toward an open trade and investment model of economic development and away from

an import-substitution-industrialization economic model.

The Ministry of Economic Development and Trade of the Russian Federation requested that the

World Bank undertake studies to assess the consequences of WTO accession in Russia. This has

led to several studies of the likely impacts. Jensen, Rutherford and Tarr (2007) estimated that in

the medium term, Russia should gain about 3.3 percent per year of the value of Russian GDP (or

about $53 billion per year based on 2008 GDP at market exchange rates). In the long term, when

the positive impact on the investment climate is incorporated, the gains should increase to about

11 percent per year of the value of Russian GDP (or about $177 billion per year at market

exchange rates).5 Based on the econometric estimates of the gains from an open economy trade

regime, these estimated gains are very plausible.6

Rutherford and Tarr (2008) examined household and poverty impacts and found that virtually all

households should gain from WTO accession. They find that skilled labor and urban households

gain relatively more than average due to the increase in foreign direct investment in the skill

intensive business services sectors. Rich households should gain less than the average household,

since increased competition from foreign investment results in capital gaining less than labor. The

poorest households are estimated to gain at about the level of the average household.

Given the vast geographic diversity of Russia, Rutherford and Tarr (2010) estimated how impacts

would vary across the regions of Russia in a ten region model of Russia. They estimate that all

regions should gain substantially, but the regions that will gain the most are those that are most

successful at attracting foreign direct investment and creating a good investment climate. 7

5 Russia’s GDP at market exchange rates is estimated at $1.61 trillion by the World Bank; $1.68 trillion by

the IMF and $1.76 trillion by the CIA, making it either the eighth or ninth largest economy in the world.

Based on Purchasing Power Parity (PPP) exchange rates, Russia’s GDP was $2.3 trillion in 2008, making it

the sixth largest economy in the world—larger than the UK or France. At PPP exchange rates, the

estimated gains per year for WTO accession would rise in the medium term to about $76 billion per year

and $253 billion per year in the long term.

6 A welfare increase of 3.3 percent of GDP is quite plausible in the context of the estimated gains from

trade liberalization from econometric studies. First, Rutherford and Tarr (2002) have shown that a

permanent increase of between 0.4 percent and one percent in the growth rate of an economy corresponds

to a welfare increase of between 10 and 35 percent. Sachs and Warner (1995) estimate that open economies

have grown about 2.45 percent faster than closed economies, with even greater differences for open versus

closed economies among developing countries. They note that trade liberalization is often accompanied by

macro stabilization and other market reforms, and their open economy variable can be picking up these

other effects as well. But they argue that trade liberalization is the sine qua non of the overall reform

process, because other interventions such as state subsidies often are unsustainable in an open economy.

Moreover, Frankel and Romer (1999) have shown that adjusting for the simultaneity bias in cross country

regression studies such as Sachs and Warner, does not reduce the estimated impact of openness on growth.

More recently, using time series data on individual countries, rather than cross-country growth regressions,

Wacziarg and Welch (2009) find compelling evidence that countries grow about 1.5 percentage points

faster after they liberalized trade.

Rodrik, Subramanian and Trebbi (2004) and Bolaky and Freund (2008) have highlighted the importance of

good institutions to economic growth. Bolaky and Freund have shown that in 25% of the countries with the

worst business and labor regulations, open trade can harm growth. On the other hand, for the 75% of the

countries with the best business and labor regulations, open trade has an even stronger beneficial impact on

growth than previous authors have found. But Dollar and Kraay (2003) find evidence that trade is more

important than institutions in the medium terms; and Rodrik, Subramanian and Trebbi have shown that

trade liberalization can improve institutions while Ades and di Tella (1999) find evidence that increased

trade leads to reduced corruption.

7 They estimate that as a percent of consumption in the medium term the three regions in their model that

will gain the most are the Northwest (11.2 percent), St. Petersburg (10.6 percent) and Far East (9.7 percent)

while the Urals (6.2%) gains the least.

Responding to a request from the Ministry of Communications, Jensen, Rutherford and Tarr

(2006) examined the impacts on the telecommunications sector of Russia. They find that skilled

workers in the telecom sector will gain substantially from FDI. Russian firms that become part of

joint ventures with foreign investors will likely preserve or increase the value of their

investments; but Russian capital owners in the telecom sector who remain wholly independent of

multinational firms will likely see the value of their investments decline. Households dependent

on income from these types of firms may lose from WTO accession. Rutherford and Tarr (2008)

estimate a similar distribution of the gains in the other business services sectors.

In summary, these studies indicate that Russia will reap substantial gains from WTO accession,

the benefits are widespread and will reduce poverty, those regions that establish a better

investment climate will reap greater gains from WTO accession, and, crucially, most of the gains

are due to Russia’s commitments to implement its own reforms. The commitments to implement

reforms in the services sectors are the most important of Russia’s own reforms that produce the

gains.

These authors do not find that WTO accession will contribute positively to the diversification

objective of the Russian Government. The sectors they estimate to expand the most are nonferrous

metals, ferrous metals and chemicals. While it is light industry, food processing and

construction materials that they estimate are likely to contract. In the concluding section of this

article, we discuss how the diversification objective can be most effectively achieved.

The estimates suggest that less than 10 percent of the gains come from improved market access

for Russian exporters. After all, Russia has negotiated most favored nation status or better with all

its significant trading partners. While Russian exporters will be accorded additional legal benefits

in antidumping cases once Russia is a WTO member, and this is the source of the gains they

estimate, many economists are cynical regarding the fairness of antidumping proceedings. This

suggests that we should not expect very significant differences in determinations against Russian

exporters in antidumping cases, and consequently improved market access in export markets

cannot be the source of significant gains to Russia from WTO accession.8

Given that the benefits to Russia of WTO accession come from its own internal reforms, some

infer from this fact that Russia will gain little from WTO accession—since Russia could

unilaterally implement these reforms. There are several reasons why we take the opposite view—

that the process of WTO accession is a unique historical opportunity to achieve reform.

8 In addition, members of the WTO obtain rights in international trade. Members are granted permanent

most-favored nation status to the markets of other member states. So Russia will not have to be concerned

about annual renewals of Most Favored Nation status. Members are also able to use the WTO’s dispute

settlement procedures to protect their trade interests, such as in antidumping cases. Trade disputes among

WTO members are resolved based on WTO legal agreements under which smaller countries have the

potential to win disputes against large countries. All WTO agreements require unanimous consent of all the

members, and this helps provide a voice for the smaller member countries. On the other hand, nonmembers

will be influenced by the new rules of this dominant organization in international trade, without a

voice in their formation.

The key reason that WTO accession is important is the political economy dimension. Given the

concentrated benefits to industries that achieve protection, industry groups will typically lobby

for protection. On the other hand, since the benefits to consumers are diverse and less

concentrated, they typically do not lobby against protection, but hope others with similar interests

will lobby on their behalf. This so called “free rider problem” in political decision-making results

in an absence of representation of the views of the consumer and broader economic interests in

political discussions of tariffs. Lobbying and political economy considerations often allow special

interests to strongly influence policy so that reforms are slow. WTO accession, however, requires

across the board reform in many sectors, and the pressure of a WTO negotiation engages policy

makers at the highest levels of government. Experience has shown that high- level policy-makers,

who have the economy-wide interest in mind, will often intervene to impose reform on slow

moving Ministries. In the case of Russia, the process began to move when then President Putin

made WTO accession a priority in his first term.

We explain in the next section that it is difficult to argue that Russia would have made reforms as

widespread and as deep as it has without the external pressure of WTO accession. Reforms are

accomplished in the context of WTO accession that would not normally be achieved so quickly.

That is, WTO bindings and external pressure make it easier for a government to adopt a trade

policy designed to promote growth and poverty reduction. Moreover, unlike unilateral reforms,

once a country commits to a reform at the WTO, it is bound by an international commitment that

is difficult to reverse in the future by a less reform minded government. The process of

negotiating bilateral market access with the countries on its WTO Working Party on Accession

has led to a dramatic increase in reforms regarding the Russian trade and foreign investment

regimes, and thereby has helped Russia move toward an open economy model of economic

development.

III. Russian Commitments to Foreign Exporters and Investors9

Non-Agricultural Market Access (NAMA)

Russia agreed to reduce its bound MFN tariffs to about 8 percent on average. The calculations of

Shepotylo and Tarr (2008) show that for 2005, Russia’s MFN tariffs were about 12.1 percent on a

simple average basis or 14 percent on a trade weighted basis, where we have taken into account

the ad valorem equivalents of Russia’s specific tariffs. Thus, a cut of the average Russian tariff to

8 percent implies a decline of about 50 percent on average.

Services Commitments

9 The United States Trade Representative (2006) has released five “Fact Sheets” with details of Russian

commitments as part the US-Russia bilateral protocol. See this source for further details.

The business services sectors have been the subject of some of the most intense negotiations

associated with Russian accession. Russia has made numerous commitments in this area. Some of

the key concessions are the following. Russia has agreed to increase the quota on the maximum

share that foreign banks and insurance companies can attain from 15 percent to 50 percent, and

Russia will phase out the prohibition on foreign participation in mandatory insurance lines.

Russia reportedly agreed to terminate the Rostelecom monopoly on long distance fixed line

telephone services as part of the Russia-EU bilateral agreement. (There are multinational

telephone operators already operating in the Russian mobile telephone market.) Russia will

ensure national treatment and market access for a wide variety of professions, including lawyers,

accountants, architects, engineers, marketing specialists, and health care professionals. Foreign

owned companies will be permitted to engage in wholesale and retail trade, franchise sectors and

express courier services. 10 The European Union has negotiated intensely for the rights of

companies other than Gazprom to construct a gas pipeline; but no success in this area has been

reported.

In banking, opposition galvanized around the branch banking issue. Russia was willing to allow

subsidiaries of international banks. Subsidiaries must be registered as Russian entities, and the

capital requirements would be based on capital in the Russian entity. Branches, however, do not

have a separate legal status or capital apart from their foreign parent bank. In general, entry into

banking services in a country is easier when branches are permitted and the U.S. Treasury has

been attempting to assure branch banking is permitted in all countries admitted to the WTO. The

Russian central bank maintained that it could not regulate or supervise branches adequately and

that depositors would therefore be at risk.

Banking interests in Russia succeeded in getting then President Putin himself to say that branch

banking was a deal breaker for Russian WTO accession. Based on its bilateral agreement with

the U.S., Russia succeeded in avoiding a commitment on branch banking, becoming the only non-

LDC acceding country to avoid such a commitment.11 Like many items in accession negotiations,

succeeding in avoiding a commitment is a pyrrhic victory as Russia will lose the benefits from

greater foreign direct investment. Nonetheless, multinational banks, operating as subsidiaries,

have greater market access and national treatment rights under the bilateral U.S.-Russia

agreement and Russia should benefit from greater involvement of multinational banks in Russia

over time.

Agriculture Issues

Agricultural issues have been among the most contentious in Russia’s WTO accession

negotiations. The key unresolved issue is agricultural subsidies, which we discuss below. Russia,

however, has made considerable commitments in market access as well as sanitary and phytosanitary

negotiations. For beef, pork and poultry exports, the disputes with the U.S. were among

10 See Tarr (2007) for details.

11 Russia agrees to reopen discussions on this issue upon consideration of membership in the OECD.

the most significant. Under its bilateral market access agreement with the U.S. however, Russia

has made substantial concessions.

For poultry and pork products, instead of joint inspection of facilities, Russia agrees to allow the

U.S. Department of Agriculture-Food Safety and Inspection Service to inspect and certify new

facilities or facilities that need to remedy a deficiency. Regarding beef, Russia and the U.S. agree

to timely joint inspections of all facilities that will export to the Russia. Once a joint inspection

has been completed, the inspection process applying to poultry and pork exporters will apply.

Additional significant commitments were made to the U.S. regarding risk mitigation for trichinae

in pork and in modern biotechnology products

IV. Are There Excessive Demands on Russia Due to Political Considerations?

The allegation that demands on Russia are either political or excessive by the standards of other

countries that have acceded to the WTO have been repeated frequently and have been come to be

believed by many observers. We believe, however, that the evidence contradicts this allegation.

Aside from a couple of well publicized cases where unusual demands were placed on Russia,12

the demands placed are Russia are typical of the WTO accession process in the past ten years.

The process of acceding to the WTO since 1998 is a difficult one in which all acceding countries

have been asked to take on very significant commitments to foreign exporters and investors. In

comparison with the commitments of these countries, the commitments that are reported for

Russia do not appear excessive.

Goods

In goods, Russia has agreed to bind its tariffs at an average tariff level of 8 percent, after an

adjustment period (USTR, 2006). This is a slightly higher average bound tariff on goods than

most countries that have acceded to the WTO since 1998 (see WTO, 2005). The average tariffs

for other acceding countries are: Saudi Arabia, 10.5 percent; Former Yugoslavian Republic of

Macedonia, 6.2 percent; Armenia, 7.5 percent; Chinese Taipei, 4.8 percent; China, 9.1 percent;

Moldova, 6.0 percent; Croatia, 5.5 percent; Oman, 11.6 percent; Albania, 6.6 percent; Georgia,

6.5 percent; Jordan, 15.2 percent; Estonia, 7.3 percent; Latvia, 9.4 percent; Kyrgyz Republic, 6.7

percent.13 Thus, by the standards of countries that have acceded to the WTO in the last eight

years that are not “Least Developing Countries,” Russia appears to have concluded market access

12 One unusual demand on Russia was the pressure on Russia to unify its domestic and export price of

natural gas. This demand, which occupied negotiators for considerable time and was eventually dropped by

the European Union, would have imposed a very high cost on Russia (see Tarr and Thompson, 2005).

13 Two of the “Least Developed Nations” acceded with relatively high bound tariffs: Cambodia, 17.7

percent; and Nepal, 23.7 percent. But the WTO accords a preferential status to developing countries.

negotiations with bound tariffs slightly higher than average, especially in comparison to the other

Transition Countries, i.e., no excessive demands from the Working Party here.

Services

In the area of services, no simple measure like an average tariff is available. But an examination

of the table of commitments of the countries that have acceded to the WTO since 1998 (WTO,

2005, table 5) shows that that all of them have assumed a rather high and comprehensive level of

commitments, in terms of sectors included. On a qualitative basis, a more detailed analysis of

banking and insurance (Tarr, 2007) does not suggest an above average level of commitments in

these important sectors. On the contrary, Russia has been able to avoid a commitment to branches

of banks, unlike almost all of these countries.

Agriculture

The level of agricultural support permitted has become a major point of controversy for Russia.

Russia is attempting to negotiate a high permitted “Aggregate Measure of Support” (AMS) in

agriculture. We note, however, despite the increase in Russian agricultural subsidies in recent

years, the de minimis level of subsidies under WTO rules should allow Russia to subsidize at its

present levels or higher.

Green Box Subsidies—Unconstrained

First, the WTO allows without constraint an extensive list of subsidies in agriculture that are not

considered trade distorting—the so-called “Green Box” subsidies. Green Box subsidies include a

wide range of publicly funded measures including research and development, pest control,

general and specialist training, extension and advisory services, inspection services for health and

sanitary reasons, marketing and promotion services, infrastructure services, including electricity,

roads and environmental expenditures, targeted support to low income population through food

stamps or subsidized prices, direct payments to producers to support income provided it has

minimal trade-distorting features, crop insurance subsidies for natural disasters, adjustment

assistance through producer retirement programs and indirect income support not related to

prices. The world-wide trend is to move agricultural support away from trade-distorting subsidies

toward Green Box measures. In part, this is because it is generally recognized that trade-distorting

subsidies are a highly inefficient way of helping agricultural producers compared with Green Box

measures. And Green Box measures, which focus on research and development and agricultural

services to improve productivity, are more effective at creating a competitive agricultural sector

in the long run.

Amber Box Subsidies—the de minimis level

Second, trade distorting subsidies to production—the so-called “Amber Box” subsidies—are

constrained; but the de minimis levels of support allow developing countries to provide state

support to agriculture of up to 20 percent of the value of aggregate agricultural output. Amber

box subsidies are defined as either product specific or non-product specific. For developing

countries, if product specific amber box subsidies are below 10 percent of the gross value of

agricultural production in the specific sector, the level of support is considered de minimis. In

addition, a developing country may provide further amber box support on a non-product specific

basis and have it be defined as de minimis provided the non-product specific support is not above

ten percent of the gross value of aggregate agricultural production. Countries can self-classify

their support between product and non-product specific support, subject only to dispute

settlement, which is rarely used in this area.14

As part of their accession commitments, however, the countries of the former Soviet Union that

have acceded to the WTO have had to agree to accept developed country de minimus limits

(sometimes with an adjustment period). That is, Estonia, Lativa, Lithuania, Georgia, Armenia,

Moldova and the Kyrgyz Republic have all accepted five percent limits on product specific

agricultural subsidies plus and 5 percent limits on non-product specific support. Without specific

knowledge of the Russian negotiations, it is likely that Russia is being pressured to accept the

same smaller de minimus limits on Amber Box subsidies. If Russia were to agree to this, it

would mean that independent of Russia’s declaration as a developed or developing country postaccession,

the de minimis level of agricultural subsidies would be developed country de minimis

levels.

The Aggregate Measure of Support (AMS) and the Russian support level

Incumbent members of the WTO, like the European Union, Canada, the United States and

Norway, have a base period for trade-distorting agricultural subsidies that allows more substantial

trade-distorting subsidies than the de minimis levels. The precedent among acceding countries,

however, is that the three year period prior to accession forms the base period for permitted tradedistorting

subsidies, and trade-distorting subsidies are negotiated down from that base. Russia

failed in the bilateral discussions to achieve its objective of defining 1992-1994 as the base period

for trade-distorting agricultural subsidies. Russia now hopes that it will be able to negotiate about

$9 billion in trade distorting subsidies.

The total value of state support to Russian agriculture in 2008 was about 163 billion rubles (or

about 6.5 billion US dollars).15 The Ministry of Finance data includes all support to agriculture,

including many items that would be considered Green Box support, i.e., unconstrained support.

The total value of Russian agricultural output in 2008 was 1776 billion rubles (including

agriculture, hunting and, fishing).16 Subsidies of 163 billion rubles are about nine percent of the

value of agricultural output. The $9 billion in Amber Box subsidies sought by Russia is about

12-13 percent of the aggregate value of Russian agricultural output.

14 The de minimis levels of support for developed countries are one-half the allowed levels for

developing countries. Post-accession, countries self declare whether they are developed or developing.

15 http://www1.minfin.ru/ru/budget/federal_budget/08-10/.

16 See the Rosstat website for this information at:

http://www.gks.ru/bgd/free/b00_25/IssWWW.exe/Stg/dvvp/i000610r.htm

If Russia were constrained by developed country de minimus levels post accession, it would still

be permitted the $9 billion in agricultural support, provided about $2 billion of that support is

provided through Green Box subsidies. According to the reports in the press, it is likely that at

least $2 billion of existing support could be classified as Green Box support.

In summary, the de minimis levels of agricultural support in Russia appear to allow Russia to

subsidize agriculture at its present level of support or considerably more to the extent Green Box

subsidies (which are more effective at helping farmers) are used. Thus, unless Russia seeks to

use Amber Box subsidies to a significantly larger extent than at present, we do not understand

why this is a crucial issue for Russia.

V. Remaining Issues in Russian Accession as an Independent Country

Often the most difficult issues remain at the end of the accession negotiations. Although Russia

has resolved some of the most contentious, (such as gas pricing and branch banking where Russia

achieved its objectives in the negotiations) several difficult issues remain.

The Conflict with Georgia

The conflict between Russia and Georgia regarding Abkhazia and South Ossetia has spilled over

to the WTO negotiations. Georgia signed its bilateral agreement on Russian WTO Accession in

2004, then withdrew its support for Russia’s WTO accession. Moreover, Georgia has objected to

the agenda of the multilateral meetings and thereby blocked any formal meetings of the Working

Party on Russian WTO accession. The Working Party has been meeting on an “informal basis” to

make progress on Russian WTO accession. Agreement on Russia’s intellectual property regime

was accomplished in this manner.

Article XII of the WTO Articles on Accession states that “Decisions on accession shall be taken

by the Ministerial Conference. The Ministerial Conference shall approve the agreement on the

terms of accession by a two-thirds majority of the Members of the WTO.”

Based on the two-thirds majority rule on accession in Article XII, Russia has apparently

investigated whether it can by-pass Georgia based on this two-thirds majority rule pertaining to

accessions. As a practical matter, the two-thirds majority rule is an illusion and all accession

decisions are taken by consensus (by unanimity) as are all other decisions of the WTO (except

dispute settlement). The Working Party would have to write a final report on Russia’s WTO

accession, without which the matter of Russia’s WTO accession will never come to a vote before

the WTO Ministerial Meeting. Just as Georgia has been able to block the Working Party from

meeting, Georgia will be able to block the report from going to the Ministerial. So again,

consensus is required and Georgia has a blocking vote. This implies that for Russia to accede to

the WTO, Georgia will have to agree.

Agriculture

We have discussed this issue above so only briefly discuss it here. Russia is having difficulty

achieving its objective of about $9 billion in permitted trade distorting subsidies. Other countries,

like Kazakhstan and Azerbaijan, would like similar departures from the WTO precedent. If the

Working Party allows Russia a larger trade-distorting subsidy than suggested by precedent, it will

have a more difficult time negotiating previous limits with subsequent applicants for WTO

membership. Australia and New Zealand are likely to resist a change in precedent that would

allow an increase in the trade-distorting subsidies.

Export Taxes on Timber—Dispute with the European Union

In early 2007, the Russian government announced an increase in the export tax on timber, to be

phased in over 18 months. Export taxes on softwood or poplar timber, which, in early 2007, were

the greater of either 6.5 percent or 4 euros per cubic meter were progressively raised reaching the

maximum of 25 percent or 15 euros per cubic meter as of April 1, 2008. The plan was to increase

the export taxes further in January 2009 to the maximum of 80 percent or 50 euros per cubic

meter.17 To date, however, the Russian Government has postponed implementation of the 80

percent export tax. The increase in the export tax is part of the effort by the Russia government to

diversify its industry and is intended to dramatically reduce log exports, provide cheaper inputs to

the wood processors and invite foreign direct investment to develop its wood processing sector.

Finland, which is the most heavily impacted by the export tax measure, has strenuously objected

to the export taxes. Sweden also opposed the export taxes. As bilateral talks with Russia failed,

these two countries succeeded in getting the EU to negotiate the matter as part of Russia’s WTO

accession negotiations, but the issue remains unresolved. 18

Regarding Russia’s national interest in the matter, increasing value added is not a goal to be

pursued at any cost. Bananas could be grown at exorbitant costs in greenhouse conditions in

northern Siberia if value added were the only criterion. Rather production according to

comparative advantage is the appropriate criterion. But the strong concerns from Finland,

suggest that Russia has some monopoly power in its trade with Finland, and given the

competitive nature of the logging industry, an export tax would be needed to exploit it.

By extending the model of Tarr and Thomson (2005), Khramov, Korableva and Kovaleva (2008)

have shown that Russia does have an optimal export tax to exploit its monopoly power on exports

of timber. However they estimate that the export tax is about 11.5 percent. Thus, the actual export

tax applied since April 2008 is more than twice the optimum level and dramatically less than the

17 In 2005, Russia introduced a 6.5 percent export tax on logs. As of July 1, 2007, export taxes were raised

to the maximum of 20 percent or 10 euros per cubic meter. As of April 1, 2008. export taxes were raised to

the maximum of 25 percent or 15 euros per cubic meter.

18 See “Russia and Finland at loggerheads over timber taxation,” International Centre for Trade and

Sustainable Development. Available at: http://ictsd.net/i/news/bridges/27601/.

approximately 80 percent that is proposed for the future. When the costs to the logging industry

are taken into account, the timber export tax imposes a lot more costs on the Russian economy

(and the logging sector in particular) than benefits.

Rules on State Trading Enterprises

The position of the Russian negotiators is that Russia is willing to accept the usual restraints on

state trading enterprises for WTO members. Russia objects, however, to demands by the U.S. for

more stringent restraints on state trading enterprises.

VI. The Attempt to Accede as a Customs Union—what does it mean for Russia’s trade

policy in the future?

The Customs Union and WTO Accession

In June 2009, Prime Minister Putin announced that Russia would abandon its effort to join the

WTO as a single country and seek membership as part of a three country customs union with

Kazakhstan and Belarus. President Medvedev, however, and some officials from his office

promptly indicated that single country accession was still the preferred method for Russian

accession.19 Considerable confusion prevailed in the Russian government until October 15, 2009,

when Maxim Medvedkov, the lead Russian negotiator on WTO accession, announced that the

three countries would seek to accede to the WTO as single countries, rather than seek accession

as a customs union.

Although Russia, Belarus and Kazakhstan have returned to independent accession negotiations,

Mr. Medvedkov announced that they hope to accede to the WTO on the basis of a common

external tariff. That is due to be implemented from January 1, 2010. 20 The return to the

negotiating table as independent countries apparently reflects the reality of the enormous

complexity that negotiating as a common customs entity entails.21 If the three countries were to

jointly apply to the WTO for accession as a customs union, a new WTO Working Party on the

accession of the customs union would have to be formed. This new Working Party would have to

be convinced that the conditions of agreement would be applied throughout the three countries of

the customs union. These commitments include, but are not limited to: commitments on bound

tariffs; rights of foreign investors in services (a rather complicated area of negotiation); Technical

Barriers to Trade (TBTs); Sanitary and Phyto-Sanitary Measures (SPS); Trade Related

Investment Measures, agricultural trade distorting subsidies, and intellectual property

19 See http://blog.taragana.com/n/russian-president-wto-membership-via-customs-union-with-kazakhstanbelarus-

problematic-105904/

20 See Russia Scraps WTO customs union bid, Financial Times, October 15, 2009.

http://www.ft.com/cms/s/0/cd78250c-b9b2-11de-a7470144feab49a.html?catid=6&SID=google)

21 In its Russia Economic Report, the World Bank (2009) warned of the difficulties of acceding to the WTO

as a customs union.

commitments. This is sufficiently difficult that no customs union has acceded to the WTO, only

individual countries.

The biggest problem with the October 2009 announcement is the statement, repeated by

Belarusian representatives,22 that the three countries would accede to the WTO simultaneously.

Since Belarus is far behind Russia in its WTO accession negotiations, simultaneous accession

would mean that Russia would have to wait, potentially many years, until Belarus is ready to join

the WTO.

Mr. Medvedkov announced that the common external tariff would not violate any bound tariff

agreement at the WTO, The chief negotiator for Kazakhstan, however, Zhanar Aitzhonova,

implicitly acknowledged that the customs union tariff will violate commitments Kazakhstan has

made in its bilateral market access agreements on its WTO accession.

Prospects for the Customs Union

As with earlier agreements on the EURASEC customs union, questions remain regarding whether

the common external tariff will be implemented outside of Russia. As explained in detail in

Michalopoulos and Tarr (1997a; 1997b), in EURASEC the tariff was the Russian tariff that

protected Russian industry and made the other countries pay higher prices for these Russian

goods compared with cheaper third country imports. Thus, implementation of the common

external tariff outside of Russia was reportedly only between 50 and 60 percent of the tariff lines,

depending on the country. In the current three country customs union, a formal supranational

tariff setting authority should begin operating in January 2010, but the common external tariff has

already been established. As in EURASEC, the tariff structure is likely heavily biased in favor of

protecting Russian producers. Thus, there is reason to believe that over time, we may see a lack of

implementation of the customs union common external tariff in the partner countries of Russia.

While negotiation of a common external tariff is a notoriously difficult problem in a customs

union, there are areas where the members of the customs union could potentially provide

substantial trade benefits to each other. Two such areas include improving trade facilitation and

the reduction of non-tariff barriers. The members of the customs union could work in these winwin

problems, independent of the common external tariff.

VII. Russian WTO Accession and the Jackson-Vanik Amendment

The Jackson-Vanik Amendment of the U.S. requires an annual review of Russian emigration

policies in order for the U.S. to grant Most Favored Nation (MFN) status to Russia (and other

former communist countries). This is a significant irritant to Russia, but the U.S. does not

presently have any commercial pressure on it to remove Jackson-Vanik. Once Russia becomes a

WTO member, however, there will be commercial pressure on the U.S. from its own exporters

22 See NewsBY.org, October 19, 2009 at http://www.newsby.org/by/2009/10/19/text10968.htm.

and investors to remove Jackson-Vanik. Consequently, the U.S. will almost certainly remove

Jackson-Vanik after Russian WTO accession.

The WTO requires that permanent MFN status be granted to all members. Thus, the provisions of

Jackson-Vanik are inconsistent with MFN treatment required by the WTO. The U.S. has two

options once Russia becomes a member of the WTO: (1) eliminate Jackson-Vanik; or (2) invoke

the "non-application principle" of the WTO. For newly acceding countries, a member of the

WTO can opt out of WTO commitments with respect to the newly acceding country if it invokes

the “non-application” principle. If the U.S. were to invoke the non-application principle against

Russia, it means that the U.S. would refuse to honor its WTO obligations to Russia. But nonapplication

is reciprocal. So the U.S. would not have any assurance that its exporters or investors

would be treated in Russia according to Russia's WTO commitments.

In practice, the U.S. has dropped Jackson-Vanik on all countries that have acceded to the WTO

with one exception. In the cases of Albania, Bulgaria Cambodia, Estonia, Latvia and Lithuania,

Jackson-Vanik was repealed prior to accession. In the cases of Mongolia, Armenia, Georgia,

Kyrgyzstan it was repealed after accession, so the "non-application" principle was invoked, but

eventually removed within a year or two. (In the case of Georgia, non-application was never

invoked since Jackson-Vanik was removed soon enough after accession.) Only in the case of

Moldova does Jackson-Vanik still apply to a country that acceded to the WTO.

Former U.S. Trade Representative Rob Portman testified before Congress in 2006 that the U.S.

will have to lift Jackson-Vanik against Russia, Ukraine and Kazakhstan in order for the U.S.

exporters and investors to gain the advantages of the commitments these countries are making at

the WTO. In the case of Ukraine, Jackson-Vanik was removed in 2006.

VIII. Foreign Direct Investment

In the first ten years of transition the inflow of foreign direct investments in Russia was very low

compared to Eastern European countries and the BRICs. This trend was reversed, however,

around 2002-2003. As fuel prices rose, FDI flows into Russia increased tenfold over time, and

Russia became one of the top countries in the world for inward FDI. By 2006, FDI inflows to

Russia even passed China in per capita terms. The dynamics of Russian outward FDI also has

some unusual features. Namely, the outflow is more significant than in other emerging economies

and started very early in the transition.

Table 1. Inflow of Foreign Direct Investments to Russia, 2000-2008

2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008

FDI, net inflows (current billions of

US dollars) 2.7 2.7 3.4 7.9 15.4 12.8 29.7 55.1 72.8

FDI as % of GDP 1.0 0.9 1.0 1.8 2.6 1.6 2.9 4.2 4.5

FDI as % of Gross Capital Formation 5.5 4.1 5.0 8.7 12.4 8.4 14.2 17.1 18.1

Sources: World Bank, World Development Indicators (2009); Central Bank of Russia

Nevertheless, starting from such a low base, the stock of FDI in Russia remains substantially less

than in some important comparator countries. The accumulated stock of FDI as a share of GDP

was 9.5% in 2006. This compares to 26% in China, 20% in Brazil and only slightly more than in

India (7.5%).

The sectoral decomposition of inward FDI is dominated by mining and quarrying (49% in 2007)

with manufacturing (17%) and real estate and business services (11%) following. The increase of

FDI in the last decade was predominantly channeled into oil and gas extraction, which increased

its dominant position in the stock of FDI. Geographically FDI flows are very concentrated:

Moscow city got 38% in 2006; the Sakhalin region got 15% and the Moscow region followed

with 10%.

The two major source countries for inflows of FDI are Cyprus (around 35% in 2006) and the

Netherlands (about the same). The later is explained by the special position of the Netherlands in

managing cross-border transactions in the fuel and gas sectors, and the former derives from

investment by Russian nationals who have capital in Cyprus (see OECD, 2008, p.16). The next

most important source country for FDI is Germany, which provided 4.4% of the inflow to Russia

in 2006. In the first half of 2009 the inflow of FDI was cut in half compared to 2008, and the list

of major FDI partners now includes China.

To some degree the significant increase in FDI inflows to Russia in the past seven years can be

explained by its macroeconomic stability, sound fiscal policy, efficient external debt management

and accumulation of foreign reserves. Infrastructure projects initiated by the state may have also

indirectly attracted FDI flows. But the major factor behind the increase in FDI was the increase in

the price of oil that made investments in the Russian oil and gas sectors more profitable.

While the large and expanding Russian domestic market can be attractive for foreign investors,

there are several very clear risks associated with the Russian economy. The first one is the high

share of output and exports in the energy sectors. Being so heavily dependent on a small number

of commodities with volatile prices makes the whole economy relatively volatile. Investors may

need to be compensated with higher returns to compensate for the volatility, which could reduce

FDI inflows. To fight the potential risks of macroeconomic instability associated with volatile oil

prices, the Government launched the Stabilization Fund of the Russian Federation in 2001.

On the other hand, in the past decade, increased government control over the economy and

problems with the slow pace of regulatory and administrative reforms impede FDI. The increase

in government control of the economy started with then President Putin’s first Administration.

President Putin became progressively more open in establishing a dominant role for the Russian

state in key sectors, including scrutiny of foreign investors in these sectors. The key piece of

legislation on this was the law on strategic sectors, approved in May 2008. It defines the

conditions under which foreign investment will operate in 42 strategic sectors, and requires prior

authorization for the foreign investor to be able to control any business entity operating in these

industries. Most of the industries on the strategic list can be aggregated in broad categories such

as military and defense industries, nuclear and radioactive hazardous materials, space and

aviation related sectors, subsoil exploration and exploitation and the fishery sector. The list also

includes industries covered by the law on natural monopolies, large scale communication

companies, TV and radio broadcasting and printing services.

The fist obvious critique of this law is the expansion of the strategic status over sectors that are

not deemed to be the strategic in many economies. Some service sectors such as TV and radio

broadcasting and printing are there so the state can control the major media outlets in Russia. The

inclusion of the industries covered by the law “On Natural Monopolies”23 is aimed at widening

state control of the Russian economy.

While the procedures required for prior clearance of foreign investments are meticulously

specified in the law, the time allowance for the official to grant the consent or declare the

transaction as being a threat to country’s security is quite long and variable: from four to seven

months. In this respect the law differs from the practice of similar legislation in many OECD

countries (OECD, 2008, p.27).

Overall, some experts point out (Gati, 2008, p.22) the positive role this law might play in

attracting FDI into the economy because the conditions the investor must take into account while

planning business transactions are explicitly defined. Nevertheless, by extending the limitations

on foreign control to too many sectors and allowing the officials too much time to reach decisions

(and time will tell if the determinations are seen as ad hoc by the foreign investment community),

the law can discourage a substantial amount of potential FDI inflows.

Another potential negative effect of the law could derive from the excessive controls on subsoil

exploration and exploitation. It limits the degree of risk sharing related to subsoil exploration. In

an era of a very high uncertainty about volatile oil and gas prices, the risks involved in the very

substantial investments in the energy field are often shared. As foreign shares of these

investments will be limited, it means that greater risks will be borne by the Russian economy.

The Russian Government has also substantially expanded its role in the economy due to the

emergence of state strategic corporations in energy, aircraft, shipbuilding, car manufacturing,

forestry and the banking sector. State enterprises absorbed many incumbent firms in these sectors

and now are often the dominant firm in the sector; these enterprises may have access to budgetary

support.24

In many of these markets, private firms may find it difficult to compete with state enterprises that

are subsidized, leading to less competition in many domestic markets-- with an inevitable decline

in efficiency, higher prices and lower quality of domestic production.

23 These industries include pipeline delivery of oil, petroleum products or natural gas, power-station

operations, railway transportation, ports and airports

24 See Gati (2008, p.17) for a similar view.

Over the past two years, the government has changed its public stance to argue for modernization

of the economy with an emphasis on foreign direct investment as the vehicle to achieve this goal.

However the increase in state control of productive assets, limitations on foreign direct

investment in several questionable areas, and increased use of import-substitution

industrialization all work against this objective. These tendencies emphasize the internal conflicts

of the current government regarding its economic policy in general and with regard to foreign

direct investment in particular.

To increase the attractiveness of Russia as a destination for FDI, the Russian Government should

work in several important directions. First, it needs to improve domestic institutions to make

Russia a better place for doing business. Russian rankings in the Doing Business Survey and

Enterprise Surveys are below the means in almost all respects and they worsened in recent

years25. In 2009, 50% of the surveyed firms in Russia mentioned corruption as a major constraint

for development. Enormous efforts should be put just to change this tendency and they involve

legislative and court reform among others.

Second, important steps should be done toward making Russia a better place for locating some

part of production process. It reflects the current situation with major FDI flows being vertical

ones and it possesses very specific requirements not just for the business climate in the country

but to a high transparency of national borders as well. In this respect Russia also falls behind its

major competitors for FDI flows being ranked only 99th out of 150 countries evaluated by

International Logistic Performance Index.26 The situation with customs is especially dreadful

with Russian ranking only 137th out of 150. Unfortunately customs reform was not on the list of

priorities aimed at modernization of Russian economy highlighted by President Medvedev in his

annual address to the Federal Assembly on November 12, 2009.

IX. Improving Customs—Any Role for Uniform Tariffs or Pre-Shipment Inspection

Given the problems in customs performance in Russia, some have recommended uniform tariffs

and pre-shipment inspection services. In our view, there is enormous merit in uniform tariffs, but

pre-shipment inspection services are likely to produce only marginal benefits at best.

In response to a request from the Russian Ministry of Trade, Tarr (1999) has analyzed the

advantages and disadvantages of a uniform tariff for Russia.27 Tarr (1999; 2002) argues that

there is little merit for Russia in the various arguments against a uniform tariff. That is, there is

25 The data from the Doing Business Surveys are available at: http://www.doingbusiness.org; and the data

from the Enterprise Surveys are available at: http://www.enterprisesurveys.org/CountryProfiles/

26 The data from the Logistics Performance Index is available at:

http://info.worldbank.org/etools/tradesurvey/mode1b.asp

27 These ideas were developed further in Tarr (2002).

little merit to the argument for diverse tariffs for strategic trade policy, for optimum revenue, for

exploitation of optimal power on imports, for negotiation leverage at the WTO or for balance of

payments purposes. On the other hand, a uniform tariff reduces the incentive to smuggle due to

elimination of the tariff peaks or to misclassify goods at customs. But by far the biggest

advantage of a uniform tariff is the political economy incentive. As the experience of Chile has

shown, since the uniform tariff eliminates the gains to individual sectors, it removes the incentive

for industrialists to lobby for higher tariffs. So the country will get a more liberal tariff regime.

Even if there is no incentive to misclassify goods due to a uniform tariff, an incentive to falsify

the valuation of the goods remains and this provides opportunities to customs officials to extract

bribes. Pre-shipment inspection (PSI) is designed to deal with that problem (among others). The

results for increased revenue collection from PSI, however, are not impressive. PSI delegates to a

foreign private firm the valuation and some other functions. The foreign firm takes its fees (about

one percent of the value of the imports). There do appear to be some increase in customs

revenues, but importers often complain that they have to go to extra expenses to undergo the PSI

and then customs puts them through inspections anyway. This raises the costs of delivering the

goods and further erodes any benefits to the home country. Crucially, PSI does nothing for

building the capacity of the home country to effectively implement a customs regime (including

customs valuation), which is the real long-run goal.

X. Conclusion: Is Russian WTO accession crucial to the international community or to

Russia?

Russian WTO Accession—Small Economic Gains to the International Community

We are skeptical the Russian WTO accession will convey significant benefits to the international

trading community. Multi-regional trade models have shown that it is the own country

liberalization that is important. That is, countries that make substantial commitments in

multilateral negotiations gain more. And those that don't make commitments gain very little from

the liberalization in the rest of the world. Numerous assessments of the Uruguay Round found

that result (See Harrison, Rutherford and Tarr. 1997; and Martin and Winters, 1996). Harrison,

Rutherford an







Дата добавления: 2015-08-30; просмотров: 351. Нарушение авторских прав; Мы поможем в написании вашей работы!



Шрифт зодчего Шрифт зодчего состоит из прописных (заглавных), строчных букв и цифр...

Картограммы и картодиаграммы Картограммы и картодиаграммы применяются для изображения географической характеристики изучаемых явлений...

Практические расчеты на срез и смятие При изучении темы обратите внимание на основные расчетные предпосылки и условности расчета...

Функция спроса населения на данный товар Функция спроса населения на данный товар: Qd=7-Р. Функция предложения: Qs= -5+2Р,где...

Конституционно-правовые нормы, их особенности и виды Характеристика отрасли права немыслима без уяснения особенностей составляющих ее норм...

Толкование Конституции Российской Федерации: виды, способы, юридическое значение Толкование права – это специальный вид юридической деятельности по раскрытию смыслового содержания правовых норм, необходимый в процессе как законотворчества, так и реализации права...

Значення творчості Г.Сковороди для розвитку української культури Важливий внесок в історію всієї духовної культури українського народу та її барокової літературно-філософської традиції зробив, зокрема, Григорій Савич Сковорода (1722—1794 pp...

Основные структурные физиотерапевтические подразделения Физиотерапевтическое подразделение является одним из структурных подразделений лечебно-профилактического учреждения, которое предназначено для оказания физиотерапевтической помощи...

Почему важны муниципальные выборы? Туристическая фирма оставляет за собой право, в случае причин непреодолимого характера, вносить некоторые изменения в программу тура без уменьшения общего объема и качества услуг, в том числе предоставлять замену отеля на равнозначный...

Тема 2: Анатомо-топографическое строение полостей зубов верхней и нижней челюстей. Полость зуба — это сложная система разветвлений, имеющая разнообразную конфигурацию...

Studopedia.info - Студопедия - 2014-2024 год . (0.011 сек.) русская версия | украинская версия