BANKING AND MONETARY POLICY
Financial intermediaries The main function of the financial institutions which make up the British banking system is to collect deposits from those with surplus cash resources and to lend the funds to those with an immediate need for them. This is the function of a financial intermediary. There are many advantages of the funds being channelled through a financial institution rather than being loaned directly by savers to borrowers. 1. Many savers want to save relatively small sums. They 2. Savers will tend to look for security — they want to 3. Financial intermediaries can use their size and exper Some of these financial intermediaries have been discussed earlier for example, insurance companies, pension funds, building societies and finance houses. In this chapter we are concerned mainly with the most important of these institutions — namely, those in the banking sector. The operations of the main banking institutions are explained later in this chapter. The various services provided by banks are summarised below (a) The provision of safe deposit faculties for money (b) The lending of money; this is the most profitable (c) The issuing of banknotes: in England and Wales this (d) The provision of efficient money transmission ser In addition to these basic functions, modern banks provide a wide range of other financial services, several of which are described later in this chapter. The British banking system 1. The Bankers' Clearing House The transmission of payments by means of cheques creates problems when the person making the payment has an account in a different bank from the person receiving the payment. The final settlement obviously requires a movement of 'money from one bank to another. In any one day there will be millions of cheques which require such inter-bank transactions to be carried out. Fortunately, many of these transfers of money will offset each other. There will be a large number of cheques drawn on accounts in Bank A that are payable to accounts in Bank B, but there will also be a large number of cheques requiring a transfer of funds in the opposite direction. Each bank in a multi-bank system will find itself in this kind of situation at the end of each day. An obvious solution is for each bank to pay (or receive) the net amount owing after the banks have totalled their claims against each other. This is the function of the Bankers' Clearing House. Cheques which are drawn on one bank but payable to another are sent to the clearing house where mutual claims are offset against one another, and the banks merely settle the outstanding amounts. These payments from one bank to another are carried out by means of cheques drawn on accounts which the clearing banks keep at the Bank of England. On an average day in 1986, some 6—7 million cheques, with a total value of f27000 million, were exchanged and cleared. The operational members of the London Clearing House are Barclays, the Midland, Lloyds, the National festminster, Coutts and Co., Williams and Glyn's, the Cooperative Bank, the Trustee Savings Bank, the National Giro Bank and the Bank of England. Non-clearing banks have agency arrangements with the clearing banks, although there are proposals to extend membership of the Bankers' Clearing House. There are three Scottish clearing banks, with their own clearing system: the Bank of Scotland, the Clydesdale and the Royal Bank of Scotland. 2. The Bank of England Most countries have a central bank, which is responsible for the operation of the banking system. The central bank in the UK is the Bank of England, which was taken into public ownership in 1946. It has many responsibilities, which are summarised below and discussed in more detail later in this chapter. (a) It is the government's bank. It handles the income (b) It is the bankers' bank. The clearing banks maintain 204
The Bank is also a banker for about 100 overseas central banks and international monetary institutions. (c) It is the central note-issuing authority for the UK and (d) It manages the national debt. This is a major (e) It is the lender of last resort. The Bank of England (f) It acts as the government's agent in the foreign (g) It has the responsibility for carrying out the govern (h) It has legal powers to supervise the operations of other banks. All banks are expected to supply the Bank of England with information about their business, and they have to respond to directives given to them by the Bank. Although the Governor of the Bank of England has a certain amount of independence and his advice is sought and heeded, the Bank is subordinate to the Treasury which may give instructions to the Governor at any time. Nationalisation and Privatisation Arguments far nationalisation 1. Monopolies. The technical conditions of production in some industries are such that competition would lead to a wasteful use of resources. Competition in the distribution of gas, electricity, water and telephone services would lead to a costly duplication of the networks of mains, pipes, cables, etc. which are required to supply these goods and services. It is also argued that the full potential economies of scale can only be obtained by one undertaking operating on a national basis. There are arguments for monopoly rather than for public ownership. The arguments for nationalisation are that (a) these basic industries should be operated in the (b) only public ownership can ensure that a powerful
2. Adjustment to changing conditions. One of the main 3. To help manage the economy. A further argument for 4. Social costs and benefits. Social costs and benefits may externalities. Generally speaking, privately-owned firms will only undertake production if private benefits (revenues) are greater than private costs; they will not take account of externalities. Nationalised industries, charged with operating in the public interest, will be under strong political and social pressures to give much more attention to externalities. They may be obliged to operate some loss making activities where social benefits are clearly greater than social costs — for example, rural, postal and transport services. The government has recognised these social obligations and, in some cases, provides subsidies for such non-commercial operations. 5. Political arguments. The motives for nationalisation are political as well as economic. It is a central theme of socialist policy that the means of production should be owned by the state. Socialists believe that public ownership enables people to exercise full democratic control over the means whereby they earn their living and provides an effective means of redistributing wealth and income more equitably. Ownership or control It is possible that the purely economic objectives of state control may be achieved without resorting to complete public ownership (i.e. nationalisation). There are various ways in which a government can control the policy and performance of privately owned enterprise. 1. it may control the industry's prices, profits, and div 2. It may take up shares in public companies and place 3. It may exercise constant supervision of the costs and 4. It may take over the wholesale stage and hence con 5, It may lay down technical specifications governing the quality and performance of the industry's products, or, through a system of licensing, control the nature of the services provided by the industry. As for some of the other objectives, a redistribution of income may be achieved by subsidies on the prices of certain goods, or by a straight transfer of income to the poor, and social costs may be dealt with by taxing those who create the social burdens (e.g. 'taxing the polluters'). These alternatives would, of course, be unacceptable to those who are politically committed to public ownership. Efficiency of public enterprise Serious problems arise in trying to judge the efficiency of public enterprise. Efficiency is a measure of success in achieving a given objective, but if the objective includes such non-measurable elements as 'operating in the best interest of the public', then any single measure of efficiency is misleading. The fact that a nationalised industry makes a profit cannot be taken as an indication of efficient operation because the industry may have used its monopoly powers to raise prices. Likewise a substantial loss does not necessarily imply inefficiency because a nationalised industry may be obliged, for social reasons, to operate unremunerative services, or its prices may be held down as part of the government's deflationary policy. Movements in labour productivity are often used as a guide to changes in efficiency, but these too can be misleading. In fact, labour productivity in several of the British nationalised industries has risen faster than the rates for industry as a whole. This measurement however does not take account of the degree of capital investment which has taken place and increases in output per unit of capital have often been relatively low. It is also difficult to use performance elsewhere as a guide to efficiency since industries in the private sector do not offer any true basis for comparison. The performance of the industry relative to the performances of the same industries in other countries may be a better guide, but here again there are many special factors to take into account. For example, in comparing productivities in coalmining the geological conditions may be very different in the countries being compared. We must remember, too, that the performances of Britain's nationalised industries have been affected by the way in which they have sometimes been used as an instrument of economic policy. Although most of them are monopolies, they cannot be too complacent because they operate in a competitive framework to the extent that there are substitutes for their goods or services (e.g. coal v. oil, gas v. electricity, road v. rail). Pricing policy The Acts which established the nationalised industries merely said that prices should be related to costs but did not specify the nature of the relationship. The simplest method of ensuring that total revenue covers total cost is to make price equal to average cost. For many of these industries, however, the costs of supplying one group of consumers can be very different from those of supplying another group. For example, in the case of the railways, the cost per passenger mile on the busy inter-City routes is much less than that on suburban branch lines where trains are normally running with a lot of excess capacity. If fares on all lines were based on average costs for the whole network, passengers on busy lines would be subsidising those on other lines. There has been much discussion on the subject of marginal cost pricing as a basis for fixing the prices of the commodities supplied by the nationalised industries. In theory, _________________________ 209 when price is equated with marginal cost we have the optimum allocation of resources. If we assume that price is a good indicator of marginal utility and that marginal cost measures the opportunity cost of the resources used to supply the marginal unit, then output should be expanded up to the point where Price = MC and no further. Additional units of output would yield satisfactions which were less than the value (in alternative uses) of the resources used to produce them, because the prices of these units would be less than their marginal costs. Unfortunately, it is very difficult to obtain any precise measure of marginal cost. Another problem with this scheme is that when the industry is operating under conditions of increasing returns, marginal cost will be less than average cost so that, if Price = MC, the industry will be making losses. If it is operating under diminishing returns, marginal cost will be above average cost so that, if Price = MC, the industry will be making abnormal profits. Nevertheless there has been some movement towards marginal cost pricing for particular products and services (e.g. the two-part tariff for electricity). In practice, the nationalised industries in the UK have not been given complete freedom in determining their pricing policies. For considerable periods they have been subject to restraint, either because the government wished to reduce inflationary pressures, or because the public has come to expect low prices in the public sector. This policy can lead to a misallocation of resources. If the private sector charges prices which yield profits while the public sector just breaks even or makes a loss, then public sector goods are under-priced, in terms of the resources used, compared with private sector goods. These 'artificially' lower prices will lead to larger quantities of public sector goods being demanded than would be the case if prices fully reflected costs in both sectors. More resources will be drawn into public sector production than consumers would 'vote' into that sector if the prices they paid were truly indicating the costs of production. Financial objectives Since the nationalised industries are state owned, the government is responsible for meeting any debts incurred by these industries. The nationalised industries do not borrow from the domestic market other than for short-term borrowing. Instead they borrow from the National Loans Fund and the government, in turn, borrows from the market. This means that the provision of external funds to meet the capital requirements of these industries has a direct effect on the borrowing of the public sector. In its attempt to control the growth of the money supply (and market rates of interest), the government is concerned to exercise strict control of public sector borrowing. The government has, therefore, introduced a system of external financial limits (EFLs) which control the amount of finance (grants and borrowing) which a nationalised industry can raise in any financial year from external sources. Further features of the financial framework which the government has created for the nationalised industries concern, (a) some target for the industries' profits, and (b) the basis on which investment decisions are made. that an adequate level of profit was essential for the well-being of the nationalised industries; it would enable them to make contributions to their investment programmes and keep down their borrowing requirements on the economy. To this end the government established a financial target for each industry. This target takes the form of some given percentage return on the net assets employed by the industry, each industry being given a different target. The second feature of financial control uses the idea of the opportunity cost of capital. Investment plans of the nationalised industries should only proceed if they are expected to earn a rate of return of 5 per cent in real terms. This figure was decided upon because it had been calculated that 5 per cent was the average real pre-tax return achieved by private investment. In other words it represented the opportunity cost of capital to the nationalised industries. In setting financial targets as a measure of performance, the government has been obliged to allow the nationalised industries much greater freedom in setting their prices. In addition the government has agreed to compensate these, industries for activities which are classified as 'public service obligations'. For example, the railways receive a grant towards the cost of keeping open lines (for social reasons) which they would otherwise choose to close. Arguments for privatisation \. Raising revenue for the government. By 1987 privatisation has generated f 25 billion in revenue for the government; it is estimated that it will raise a further f20 billion over the next four years. This revenue clearly makes it possible for the government to reduce its borrowing and to make tax cuts without reducing its own spending. However, privatisation has been likened to 'selling the family silver'. The most marketable of the nationalised industries are obviously those which are the most profitable. Once they are privatised, the state loses the future net revenues from these industries. Much depends upon how the state uses the revenues from privatisation. If it is used to finance tax cuts, will taxes have to be raised again when the privatisation programme has run its course? If it is used to reduce the government's debt, it will help to reduce the future tax burden, 2. Increased competition and efficiency. It is argued that the private sector has the spur of competition, since inefficiency is punished with bankruptcy. State-owned enterprises cannot go bankrupt because the government guarantees their borrowings. This contrast persuades the supporters of privatisation that industries and firms transferred to the pri- 212
vate sector will be more efficient organisations. They believe that managers of privatised firms will be freed from political control and interference — they will be able to charge the prices they regard as commercially sensible and to make the investments they think will pay. But in cases such as British Telecom and British Gas, competition in their main activities is virtually impossible — they are natural monopolies. The state is left with the task of ensuring that these monopoly positions are not abused. It is also extremely doubtful whether, in many cases, the threat of bankruptcy is a realistic sanction — would the government allow a major basic industry to go bankrupt? Nevertheless, in 1987, it seemed that several of the privatised firms had benefited from the discipline of the market. 3. Wider share ownership. The broadening of share ownership is another aim of privatisation. The idea is to shift ownership away from the state and large institutions towards individuals. Privatisation has been largely responsible for the increase in the number of private shareholders from 2.5 million in 1979 to more than 9 million in 1987. This has been accomplished because the sales of shares in privatised undertakings have been arranged so that small investors have been given preferential treatment. This has also been true of the workers in the industries being privatised. More than 90 per cent of British Telecom's employees bought the shares they were offered when the enterprise became a public limited company. PART 3
|